Over the
last year Uganda has latched from one major corruption scandal to
another. The paradox of our nation’s corruption is that although it goes
on with impunity, it does not go on with impunity. Although the corrupt
plunder public resources at will, the public and the state seem to be
permanently engaged in ferocious combat against them.
In the
last year we have seen a former vice president and six ministers in
court over charges of corruption. We have also seen a minister resign,
two get fired and three step aside because of allegations of corruption.
Three permanent secretaries have been interdicted and one is fighting
for his job.
I cannot
count the number of civil servants interdicted, in jail or bail for
corruption. Recently we have seen police raids on the private businesses
and homes of corrupt public servants and confiscated their property
titles, frozen their bank accounts etc.
Yet I also
know that in almost every arm of government, and in spite of all these
wars and battles against corruption, public officials are busy pillaging
national resources as if nothing is happening. Corruption seems to be
our friend and enemy, we love and loathe it in equal measure. How do we
reconcile these contradictory currents (oxymoron)?
I think
the problem is our mindset. We are taught to believe that corruption
exits in situations where you have a poor control environment (weak
procedures to guard against theft), where state institutions like
police, judiciary, Auditor General’s office etc. are weak because of
poor financing or have been compromised by the executive (lacking
independence) and where civil society is suppressed and the press
muzzled.
The
persistence of corruption in Uganda often leads us to embrace these
arguments. I write this article with a lot of humility because for many
years I was a key spokesperson of these very arguments.
In hot
pursuit of these standard arguments, our ever-generous donors have spent
time and money paying for improving the work of parliament, sent our
police officers for training abroad, sponsored legislation to increase
the powers of the Inspectorate of Government, financed “civil society”
and of course supported us in the mass media against threats from the
state.
As a
result, our anti corruption institutions and procedures in government
procurement and payments are as impregnable as the Maginot Line – that
network of fortifications built by the French in the 1930s to protect
their country against an attack from Germany. As we now know, in May
1940, the German army simply bypassed the fortifications (by going
through the Ardennes forests) and France capitulated in six weeks.
Why did
the Maginot line fail to protect France? Because the assumptions behind
it – that the defense had an upper hand, that two soldiers with a
machine gun in an entrenched position could kill a thousand enemy
soldiers – could not work in the face of the new German war strategy of
blitzkrieg, a war strategy that emphasised speed and surprise over the
static immobility which had characterised the First World War.
Similarly
the assumptions underlying the impregnable procedures and layers of
control in government procurement and payment system have been elaborate
but equally counterproductive. They assume that the multiplicity of
institutions for oversight would make collusion difficult among
officials. Instead they have bribes bigger.
Take the
example of the dubious compensation of businessman Hassan Basajabalaba.
When he initially lodged his claim, it was only Shs 22 billion.
Government set up an inter-ministerial committee composed eight
ministries and government departments. It is difficult to collude with
such a large and diverse group.
Yet that
is exactly what happened: Basajabalaba’s claim then grew to Shs 169
billion largely because these numerous layers of control increased the
number of hands he had to grease. The pensions’ scam and in the theft in
the Office of the Prime Minister also showed that oversight
institutions (Internal Audit in the ministry of finance and external
audit in the Auditor General’s office) rather than catch the thieves
actually colluded with them.
Furthermore,
our anti corruption theories (and therefore institutions we have
cultivated) assume that the supply of accountability from the leaders at
the top is a result of demand for it by citizens from below. To combat
corruption, this paradigm holds, you need to put in place mechanisms
that allow democratic oversight over the workings of public officials –
hence parliaments, free press, civil society etc. Uganda has done this
and more but corruption seems to grow in spite of (and I want to add
precisely because of) these oversight institutions.
The most
successful country in Africa in combating corruption is Rwanda. Yet we
see little or no demand for accountability from its citizens through the
press, civil society activism, political parties and parliament as we
see in Uganda. Indeed the democratic impulse in Uganda is more developed
than in Rwanda.
Yet ruling
elites in Rwanda have made fighting corruption and the delivery of
public goods and services to ordinary citizens through impersonal
institutions the corner stone of their legitimacy. In Uganda, ruling
elites have made trading patronage among themselves the central fulcrum
of democratic politics.
I share
some of my critics’ skepticism; that Rwanda’s anti corruption
credentials are fragile because they have little supporting
infrastructure within the society. Its leadership-driven approach while
commendable is too top-down and centralised. It therefore runs the risk
where change in leadership can bring the system crumbling down.
Uganda’s
fight against corruption may appear weak. But precisely because it is
diffuse among many societal forces, it has higher chances of
sustainability even in the face of changes in leadership.
While the
aforementioned risk in Rwanda is real, the lesson still is powerful.
That fighting corruption is not merely a response to pressure from
below, but needs to be buttressed by the supply of values from above.
What is missing in Uganda is not democratic oversight but values-driven
leadership.
The lesson
from Rwanda is that leadership matters, and that how electoral
coalitions are created has powerful implications on fighting corruption –
a subject I will discuss another day.
No comments:
Post a Comment